Is Crisis the Only Way to Put Innovators in Charge in Hierarchical Firm?
Abstract
The way innovators are recruited and treated within organization impacts the company’s ability to innovate. Based on literature review this research finds evidence that contrary to Schumpeterian assumptions that large companies through concentration of resources play leading role in innovation process, big hierarchical firms may fail to innovate due to recruiting patterns. Corporate hierarchy, unlike markets, tends to maintain permanent and total control of the employees and to punish and push out the least controllable. The manager has personal interest to hire and promote the most controllable employees, the ones least threatening to the manager’s status and not the most creative or innovative. This inherent feature of any hierarchy may make it unable to recruit, promote innovators and thus maintain efficient innovation process. It leads to accumulation of innovation errors and lags and to regular crises within hierarchy and of hierarchy itself due to the lack of progress and innovation. However, the crises may lead to management renewal and innovators’ promotion to decisive positions and roles. On the other hand, it means that in order to adopt and implement innovations a hierarchy requires internal or external shocks, sometimes even self-generated or exaggerated.
Keywords
Full Text:
PDFReferences
Alchian, Armen A., and Harold Demsetz (1972), Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization, The American Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 5 (Dec., 1972), pp. 777-795.
Amar A.D., and Vlatka Hlupic (2016), Leadership for knowledge organizations, European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 19 Issue: 2, pp.239-260, https://doi.org/10.1108/EJIM-12-2014-0120.
Baron, James N., Michael T. Hannan, and Diane Burton (1999), Building the Iron Cage: Determinants of Managerial Intensity in the Early Years of Organizations, American Sociological Review, Vol. 64, No. 4 (Aug., 1999), pp. 527-547.
Belyaev, Dmitry K. (1979), Destablizing selection as a factor in domestication, Journal of Heredity, 70 (5), 301-308.
Bower, Joseph L., and Clayton M. Christensen (1995), Disruptive Technologies: Catching the Wave, Harvard Business Review, 73, no. 1 (January–February 1995): pp. 43–53.
Breton, Albert, and Ronald Wintrobe (1982), The logic of bureaucratic conduct, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
Bush, Vannevar (1945), As We May Think, The Atlantic Monthly. July 1945, pp. 112-124.
Bush, Vannevar (1945), Science, the Endless Frontier, National Science Foundation, Washington, DC.
Chesbrough, Henry (2003), Open Innovation: The New Imperative for Creating and Profiting from Technology, Cambridge, MA, Harvard Business School Press.
Christensen, Clayton M. (1997), The Innovator's Dilemma: When New Technologies Cause Great Firms to Fail, Harvard Business Review Press.
Christensen, Clayton M. (2003), The Innovator's Solution: Creating and Sustaining Successful Growth, Harvard Business School Press.
Ciborra, Claudio U. (1993), Teams, Markets and Systems, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Clemons, Eric K., Sarah P. Reddi, and Michael Row (1993), The Impact of Information Technology on the Organization of Economic Activity: The" Move to the Middle" Hypothesis, Journal of Management Information Systems 10(2), pp. 9-35.
Coase, Ronald (1937), The Nature of the Firm, Economica, Blackwell Publishing, 4 (16): 386–405. doi:10.1111/j.1468-0335.1937.tb00002.x
Coase, Ronald (1960), The Problem of Social Cost, Journal of Law and Economics, Vol. 3 (Oct., 1960), pp. 1-44.
Coetzee, Daniel and Lee W. Eysturlid (2013), Philosophers of War, The Evolution of History's Greatest Military Thinkers, Praeger.
Constantiou, Ioanna and Jannis Kallinikos (2015), New games, new rules: Big data and the changing context of strategy, Journal of Information Technology 30(1), pp. 44-57 March 2015 doi: 10.1057/jit.2014.17
Cordella, Antonio (2006), Transaction costs and information systems: does IT add up? Journal of Information Technology, 21 (3), pp. 195-202.
d’Este, Pablo, Surya Mahdi, Andy Neely, and Francesco Rentocchini (2012), Inventors and entrepreneurs in academia: What types of skills and experience matter? Technovation, 32, 9-10, pp. 293- 303.
Dahlandera, L., and D. Gannb, M. (2010), How open is innovation? Research Policy, 39, pp. 699-709.
de Villepin, Dominique (2007), Le soleil noir de la puissance, 1796-1807, Perrin, Paris.
Dugan, Regina, and Kaigham Gabriel (2013), «Special Forces» Innovation: How DARPA attacks problems, Harvard Business Review, October 2013.
Freeman, Christopher and Bengt-Ake Lundvall (1988), Small Nations Facing the Technological Revolution, London, UK, Pinter Publishers.
Gans, Joshua (2016), The Disruption Dilemma, MIT Press.
Greenwald, Ted (2013), Secrets of Darpa's Innovation Machine, Forbes, February 13, 2013.
Hannah, Leslie (1998), Survival and Size Mobility among the World's Largest 100 Industrial Corporations, 1912-1995, The American Economic Review Vol. 88, No. 2, Papers and Proceedings of the Hundred and Tenth Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (May, 1998), pp. 62-65.
Hood, Bruce (2014), The Domesticated Brain, Penguin Books, London, UK.
Ings, Simon (2016), Stalin and the Scientists: A History of Triumph and Tragedy 1905–1953, Faber & Faber.
Kline, Stephen and Nathan Rosenberg (1986), An overview of innovation, In: Landau, R., Rosenberg, N. (eds.), The Positive Sum Strategy: Harnessing Technology for Economic Growth, Washington, DC, National Academy Press, pp. 275-305.
Malone, Thomas W., Joanne Yates, and Robert I. Benjamin (1987) Electronic Markets and Electronic Hierarchies: Effects of information technology on market structure and corporate strategies, Communications of the ACM 30: 484–497.
Marx, Karl (1959), Economic and Philosophic Manuscripts of 1844, Progress Publishers, Moscow.
Putnam, Robert (1993), Making democracy work: civic tradition in modern Italy, Princeton University Press, Princeton.
Rifkin, Jeremy (2011), The Third Industrial Revolution: How Lateral Power is Transforming Energy, the Economy, and the World, Palgrave MacMillan.
Rogers, Nicholas (2008), The Press Gang. Naval Impressment and its opponents in Georgian Britain, Hambledon Continuum.
Schmookler, Jacob (1966), Invention and Economic Growth, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1934), The Theory of Economic Development, Harper & Row, New York.
Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Harper & Row, New York.
Solzhenitsyn, Aleksandr (1968), The First Circle, Collins, Harvill Press.
Steiber, Annika, and Sverker Alaenge (2013), A corporate system for continuous innovation: the case of Google Inc., European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 16 Issue: 2, pp.243-264, https://doi.org/10.1108/14601061311324566.
Uusi-Kakkuri, Piia, Tiina Brandt, and Susanna Kultalahti (2016), Transformational leadership in leading young innovators – a subordinate’s perspective, European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 19 Issue: 4, pp.547-567, https://doi.org/10.1108/EJIM-12-2014-0118
Weber, Max (1978), Economy and Society: An Outline of Interpretive Sociology, University of California Press.
Williamson, Oliver E. (1985), The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, Collier Macmillan, New York, London: Free Press.
Wojtczuk-Turek Agnieszka, and Dariusz Turek (2015), Innovative behaviour in the workplace: The role of HR flexibility, individual flexibility and psychological capital: the case of Poland, European Journal of Innovation Management, Vol. 18 Issue: 3, pp.397-419, https://doi.org/10.1108/EJIM-03-2014-0027
DOI: https://doi.org/10.23954/osj.v4i1.2059
Refbacks
- There are currently no refbacks.
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.
Open Science Journal (OSJ) is multidisciplinary Open Access journal. We accept scientifically rigorous research, regardless of novelty. OSJ broad scope provides a platform to publish original research in all areas of sciences, including interdisciplinary and replication studies as well as negative results.